Second Degree Price Discrimination - BoyceWire
Second Degree Price Discrimination Definition

Second Degree Price Discrimination

Second Degree Price Discrimination Definition

WRITTEN BY PAUL BOYCE | Updated 28 December 2020

What is Second Degree Price Discrimination

Second degree price discrimination is where a firm sells at different prices based on quantity. This may include offers such as buy two, get one free, or 20 percent off when you buy six.

It is a common pricing strategy used by warehouse retailers who are able to use economies of scale to make bulk purchases, and then pass these savings onto the consumer. Examples include the likes of Costco and Sam’s club who charge a small membership fee of around $50 – $60. This provides an incentive for members to buy bulk goods in order to justify the membership fee. However, because such retailers already buy the goods in bulk, they already benefit from lower costs which are then passed onto the consumer.

Key Points
  1. Second degree price discrimination occurs when consumers receive a discount on multiple purchases.
  2. Firms are able to offer lower prices for bulk purchases as they benefit from economies of scale.
  3. Examples of second-degree price discrimination include: coupons, buy two get one free, multi-packs, and loyalty cards.

Unlike other forms of price discrimination, second-degree price discrimination requires little effort to segment customers. For instance, first-degree price discrimination requires the firm to calculate each consumer’s maximum willingness to pay. By comparison, third-degree price discrimination requires the firm to segment into groups such as age or income group. Yet second-degree price discrimination only requires the firm to segment into those who want to buy in bulk and those who do not.

It is perhaps the most effective of all the types of discrimination due to the ease by which groups can be segmented. At the same time, bulk discounts encourage consumers to spend more. For example, offers such as buy two get one free encourage consumers to purchase another so they can get a further one for free. Even though consumers may not necessarily want another, it makes the second and third seem that much cheaper.

Firms can conduct this type of price discrimination due to economies of scale. The profit margins for one unit sold are usually quite high, which means they can reduce these margins for the subsequent units in order to encourage further consumption. So although the profit margin for the second unit may not be as high as the first, the overall profit is higher than it would be had only one been sold.


Second-Degree Price Discrimination Graph

Second-degree price discrimination can be a useful pricing strategy for a number of companies. It is mainly used by companies that have high-profit margins on the first unit sold – so can therefore reduce the price for subsequent units in order to incentivize further consumption.

The graph below demonstrates the sale of ice cream tubs. The usual retail price for these is $5 per tub. At this price, there is demand for 100 of these – thereby bringing in a revenue of $500. However, once a bulk discount is applied and the price is reduced to $3.50 – demand increase to 200, which brings revenue to $700.

Second degree price discrimination graph

The firm also has to produce an extra 100 units, but due to economies of scale, it is able to produce these at a lower cost than the first. This is due to falling average costs which occur due to the bulk orders that warehouse retailers are able to trade with. Therefore, the total profits the firm makes can be higher than comparative retailers.


Second-Degree Price Discrimination Examples



Coupons

Many customers get coupons in the post or at the store as a way to encourage existing customers to come back and buy more. By offering a discount to those customers, the firm is able to attract repeat custom and increase sales. These are commonly adopted by retailers – usually in conjunction with a loyalty card. By offering coupons, customers are encouraged to come back and buy more goods from the store – albeit at a lower price.

Loyalty Cards

Loyalty cards are used by most supermarket retailers as well as restaurants and cafes. For example, some cafes offer a ticket whereby the customer receives a stamp with every visit. After 6 visits, the customer then receives a free coffee as thanks for their custom.

There are also loyalty cards at supermarkets which generally track the customer’s buying habits. They can then use that data to send through personalized promotional material to offer discounted goods. So consumers essentially sell their data to supermarkets in return for discounted prices to encourage them to come back and buy more goods.

Three for two

Three for two is a common offer that retailers use to increase sales by making subsequent purchases more appealing. Most customers only want the one good, but the thought of such a big discount on the next can attract many to spend more. This works in tandem with diminishing marginal utility whereby the customer starts to value each additional good less and less. The retailer’s solution is to offer a big discount on the subsequent purchase.

Bulk-buy

Bulk-buying is a classic form of second-degree price discrimination which offers a lower price per unit for customers that buy larger packs. For example, a can of Coca-Cola may cost $1, whilst a pack of 12 costs $6. That’s a discount of roughly 50 percent on the per-unit price as the multipack costs 50 cents each. Other examples include large tubs of ice cream, 24 packs of toilet papers, 6 pack of canned beans, and a 6 pack of doughnuts. All of which cost less per unit than individually.



FAQs on Second Degree Price Discrimination

What is second degree price discrimination?

Second degree price discrimination is where firms charge consumers a lower price for buying larger quantities.

Why does second degree price discrimination work?

Second degree price discrimination works as firms are able to pass on their benefits from economies of scale. At the same time, consumers utility diminishes for each additional unit they buy. For example, a consumer may value their first doughnut at $1.50, but they don’t really want more than just the one. Yet they would be willing to pay $0.75 for another as that value would represent the diminished utility they would receive from consuming another. So by offering additional units at a lower price, the seller is able to get around diminishing marginal utility.

Is second degree price discrimination efficient?

Second degree price discrimination is not completely efficient as it doesn’t maximise the price the consumer is willing to pay – also known as the consumer surplus. So consumers are still paying less than they would potentially be willing to pay.




Further Reading


PESTLE Analysis Definition PESTLE Analysis Definition and Template - PESTLE analysis is a strategic management tool that businesses use to identify macro-economic factors that it needs to consider. The…

PESTLE Analysis Definition and Template Read More »

Production Function Definition Production Function Definition - The production function is the calculation by which the number of inputs creates a number of outputs. In other words,…

Production Function Definition Read More »

Rational Choice Theory Definition Rational Choice Theory Definition - Rational choice theory is a concept that assumes people make rational choices which align to their own self-interest. Each individual…

Rational Choice Theory Definition Read More »